World Economy
0

East Asian Miracle Now Seen as Myth-Making

The region’s rapid growth and industrialization were simply due to high investment and labor participation rates, rather than productivity gains
Eight high-performing Asian economies consisted of Japan, Hong Kong, South Korea, Taiwan, Singapore, Malaysia, Thailand and Indonesia.
Eight high-performing Asian economies consisted of Japan, Hong Kong, South Korea, Taiwan, Singapore, Malaysia, Thailand and Indonesia.

Even before the term ‘Washington Consensus’ was popularized, it was already coming under great criticism despite the ‘counter-revolutions’ against ‘development economics’ and Keynesian economics associated with Thatcherism and Reaganomics.

At the World Bank, the Japanese executive director argued that the WC menu of policy advice and conditionalities had resulted in the 1980s’ ‘lost decade’ in Latin America and Africa. In contrast, the East Asian region had seen rapid growth and industrialization, IPS reported.

At Japanese government expense, the bank published the East Asian Miracle volume in 1993. But instead of recognizing that the WC was in fact the problem, the volume contributed to the myth-making which ensured its continued influence for years thereafter.

The EAM study’s eight high-performing Asian economies consisted of Japan, Hong Kong and three first-generation newly industrializing economies, namely South Korea, Taiwan and Singapore, and three second-generation South East Asian newly industrializing countries, namely Malaysia, Thailand and Indonesia, but excluded China.

It identified six types of state interventions in East Asia, only approving four ‘functional’ interventions, said to compensate for ‘market failures’, namely:

– ensuring macroeconomic discipline and balances;

– providing physical and social infrastructure;

– raising savings and investment rates; and

– providing good governance.

Macroeconomic Balance

Although no one recommends reckless macroeconomic policies, there is little consensus on what constitutes sound macroeconomic policy. Although most ‘neoliberal’ economists insist on maintaining macroeconomic balances, they rarely agree on what this implies, while Keynesian economists favor counter-cyclical policies to address business cycles.

For instance, inflation was generally kept under 20% in the HPAEs, but certainly not always below 10%. Single digit inflation was not a common and consistent policy priority of all HPAEs during their high-growth periods. Hence, for example, Indonesia depreciated its currency regularly for many decades.

Similarly, the fiscal balance and the current account of the balance of payments were not always strictly maintained as the Bretton Woods institutions came to insist for the developing world. Many HPAEs ran large fiscal deficits to ensure high growth.

Infrastructure

Since the 1980s, the bank has increasingly urged private provision of physical infrastructure. Except in Hong Kong, a British colony until 1993, most physical infrastructure in East Asia was provided by governments until fairly recently. HPAEs privatizing physical infrastructure provision became the basis for powerful private monopolies associated with ‘cronyism’, later blamed for the 1997-1998 Asian crisis.

Governments have been extremely important in providing social services in East Asia. But the bank recommends universal and free primary education, and does not recommend subsidization beyond the primary level, when students should bear the full costs. Hence, about half the young people of age in Korea get tertiary education, while the shares are well over a quarter in other first-generation East Asian NIEs. If East Asian NIEs had listened to the bank, their progress would have been slowed considerably.

Savings and Investments

For some, the region’s rapid growth and industrialization were simply due to high investment and labor participation rates, rather than productivity gains: ‘perspiration rather than inspiration’. While conventional economic wisdom attributes high investment rates to high savings rates, savings rates have, in fact, followed–rather than determined–investment rates in East Asia.

After all, much of the high East Asian savings rates are due to firm savings, rather than just household savings. East Asian firms were generally able to enjoy high profits due to government interventions, subsidies, tax breaks and other incentives for favored investments. Government policy also induced high reinvestment of these profits.

And contrary to the myth that East Asians are ‘culturally’ thrifty, unlike others, household savings in East Asia are not significantly higher than elsewhere, except for ‘forced savings’–for employees’ retirement as mandated by law–and for children’s education.

The notion of good governance is often used ambiguously, even tautologically. When the economy is doing well, it is attributed to good governance, and when it is not, governance is deemed to have been poor. Hence, governance does not really explain economic performance.

 

Add new comment

Read our comment policy before posting your viewpoints

Financialtribune.com